Post-Communism as a Modern or Postmodern Phenomenon?
The phenomenon of post-communist development in Europe
to this day eludes a clearly-defined conceptualisation due to its
multi-dimensionality. That said, anyone who endeavours to study post-communist
political economy is obligated to commence with a discussion of ‘the commons’
and common property resources by explaining and examining the relationship and
interplay between common property and collectivism, and the monumental impact
that both liberal and neoliberal thought have had on the social economies of
Eastern Europe following the fall of communism (Pickles, 2006). This paper aims
to provide a multi-layered critique of how post-communist growth in Europe has
been variously understood and assessed, with a focus on Romania. Said
discussion is framed within the wider debate surrounding modernity and
post-modernity, employing the writings of Jacques Derrida, Jurgen Habermas,
Zygmunt Bauman and Pierre Bourdieu. The main argument proposed in this paper is
that post-communism ought to be seen as neither a modern nor postmodern
phenomenon, but rather as part of a development along an alternative trajectory
of Western modernity; one which is characterised by a struggle for identity
reaffirmation.
Contemporary understandings of both communist and
post-communist common property resources have been shaped and molded by the
neoliberal crusade. As a result, a new definition of the commons has arisen in
Europe; one that is unable to harmonize juridical and political aspirations for
a peaceful, inclusive and tolerant European Union with a common economic project [my emphasis] and space of harmonize
markets and trade policy (Meurs, 2001). These new projects of a so-called
‘common economic union’, as well as their versions of what a public, a commons
and a universal value entail, are becoming increasingly amalgamated with
postcolonial ideas and with deeply-entrenched historical and racialized views
of common identity (Stark and Bruzst, 1998).
For many political commentators representing both
sides of the Iron Curtain, the revolutions of 1989 underscored what Vladimir
Tismaneanu (1999: 69) labeled “the triumph of civic dignity and political
morality over ideological monism, bureaucratic cynicism, and police
dictatorship. Rooted in an individualistic concept of freedom and skeptical of
all ideological blueprints for social engineering, these revolutions were (at
least at the outset) liberal and non-utopian.’’ On the contrary, other scholars
have shown far less optimism about the transition process that followed
thereafter, that is, the immediate consequences of the emerging liberalism
across the region (Dauphinée, 2003). Rather, for others, the alignment of
economic and political institutions under the umbrella of a monolithic
anti-communism highlighted the dawn of a new hegemony for the capitalist
project, and with it a refined market ideology following those of Margaret
Thatcher’s Britain’s and Ronald Reagan’s America; as Derrida (1994: 51-52)
asserted: “No one, it seems to me, can contest
the fact that a dogmatics is attempting to install its worldwide hegemony
in paradoxical and suspect conditions... This dominating discourse often has
the manic, jubilatory, and incantatory form that Freud assigned to the
so-called triumphant phase of mourning work. The incantation repeats and
ritualizes itself, it holds forth and holds to formulas, like any animistic
magic. The rhythm of a cadenced march, it proclaims: Marx is dead, communism is
dead, very dead, and along with it its hopes, its discourse, its theories, and
its practices. It says: long live capitalism, long live the market, here’s to
the survival of economic and political liberalism!’’
In essence, Derrida’s pessimism reinforces the view
that the project of ‘Westernising’ the formerly socialist countries after the
fall of the Iron Curtain in 1991 was a hegemonic one, one of the subversion of
socialist identity, and the forging of a new, neoliberal union of states with
the exercise of power inevitably skewed towards those wishing to enforce the
aforementioned ideology. This crusade was waged with a fearsome and obdurate
force by the Bretton Woods agreement and its associated transformative
institutions, most notably the International Monetary Fund (IMF), and with
their agenda to privatise collective property and to ‘liberalise’ markets
(ibid.). Consequently, this post-communist process of transition could only
refer to the advent of private property, market logics, political
individualism, and a profound devotion to the universalism of a common
neo-liberal European project (Gowan, 1996).
Furthermore, on a latent level, there appeared to be a
much broader positivist and objectivist belief in what was understood
throughout the 19th Century as the stationary state; that is, a state of generalized social balance
stemming from the manners in which rational market decisions are made by
individual social actors; for example, for Balibar (2004: 106): “The result of
this is not, of course, to render any further transformation impossible;
cultural and technological changes can, in fact, go on and even accelerate. But
transformation would henceforth occur without essential conflictuality between
classes, social groups, powers, and counterpowers, ‘systemic’ and ‘antisystemic’
forces.’’ This very much framed a “return to Europe,’’ the restitution of an
unrestricted path to democracy and capitalism in which history had come to “an
end.’’ (Fukuyama, 1992).
In Eastern Europe, this new liberalism triumphed,
often with the support of groups and individuals as varied as right-wing
communists, left-wing liberals and internationalist-free-marketeers (Vedery,
1996). The radical individualism and its associated anti-collectivism that
quickly and vigorously spread through the region denounced collectivism and
common property regimes, some which had long pre-dated communism, as barriers
to economic development and ‘efficiency’ (Pickles, 2005). Throughout this
transition process, social complexity and diversity were thought of purely through
the lens of a new universalism. Economic governance was thereafter to be
structured by price signals among so-called autonomous and equal economic
actors, and the then-existing diverse economies of socialism and capitalism
were considered to be a sign of ‘backwardness’ (ibid.). The above points of
discussion relating to the nature of post-communism and the direction that it
took after the fall of communism in 1991, broadly speaking, form part of
overarching debates about the nature of modernity and its relationship with
politics, which the following section of this paper seeks to address.
The majority of responses to the issue of the collapse
of communism in Europe, Central and Western Asia have accounted for socialist
and post-socialist experience through Western sociological frames of reference
(Ray, 1997). This very much reflects the way in which sociological theory has
largely been founded upon the experience of modernity in North America and
Western Europe, and it has subsequently tended to conceive of state-socialist
systems as variants, albeit deviant ones, of familiar social forms, such as
‘industrial society.’ (Ray, 1996). Consequently, with regard to post-communism,
the debate over modernity and postmodernity revolves around the question of
whether the “civilizational distance within Europe is at stake,’’ (Zybertowicz,
1994), that is, whether the former eastern and western sectors now share a
common culture and trajectory (ibid.). The crisis of communism has often
regularly been understood by scholars as highlighting a crisis endemic to the
modernist project in general. This warrants an examination of two popular
claims: first, that communism was the epitome of modernity, and secondly that
the crisis of communism thereby foreshadows a crisis of modernity per se.
The first claim stems in part from Weberian notions of
bureaucratization. In a Weberian vein, communism has been viewed as a
nightmarish form of modernity; for example, Zygmunt Bauman (1992) adopts a
Promethean outlook on modernity, which starkly contrasts with the fluid,
differentiated and anesthetized cultural forms of postmodernity. For Bauman
(1992: 166-167), “communism was modernity in its most determined mood and most
decisive posture... purified of the last shred of the chaotic, irrational, the
spontaneous, the unpredictable.’’ Soviet modernism, therefore, was associated
with gigantism, Fordist mass production and unrelenting consumption; in other
words, an extensive, corporatist and rationalized state holding a secular,
etatist ideology (Murray, 1992).
Now, if communism was the epitome of modernity, then
the crisis of communism could serve as the trigger to a generalized crisis of
modernity or, at least as Kumar (1995: 151) points out, the end of communism
and the end of modernity perhaps possess an “elective affinity’’ for one
another. Crook et. al (1994: 42) develop this point even further by arguing
that Soviet-type societies were essentially variants of an industrial society
which is currently converging with the West in a ‘crisis of corporatism,’
marked by decentralization, new social movements, privatization and a
‘shrinking state’, deregulation and globalization. Furthermore, Bauman (1992)
argues that as a result of the allure of the postmodern consumer society in the
West, the ‘obsolete head-per-steel’ philosophy was no match for the narcissistic
culture of self-enhancement, self-enjoyment and instant gratification.
Consequently, postmodernism has the advantage of
releasing new energies and subversive forces. However, to say that there is an
‘elective affinity’ between post-communism and postmodernism are somewhat
misguided. For instance, Bauman’s (1992) nightmarish vision of modernity as
being characterised by carceral power stresses ‘discipline’ at the expense of
the contrary tendency towards ‘liberty’ (Wagner, 1994). Not only is the
implementation of disciplinary systems generally more slapdash, partial and
fragmented than Bauman suggests, but they are also dulled by the countervailing
power with which those who are subject to them are able to develop
Rather, a more persuasive argument than that of
postmodernization is that the fall of communism opened up new spaces of
struggle for modernity (Ray, 1997).
As Eisenstadt (1992) indicates, the anti-communist revolutions occurred within
already modernized societies, and the rebellions did not topple
traditionalistic ancient regimes.
Instead, regime changes took place within the confines of existing political
institutions and were ratified by legal frameworks of the outgoing states
(ibid.). In a similar view, Habermas (1994: 62) conceives of the
Eastern-European Revolutions of 1989 as ‘revolutions of recuperation’, ‘overcoming
distance’ with Western Europe. Contrary to the classical revolutions of
modernity, such as the American, French and Russian revolutions, which were
oriented towards the future, the anti-communist revolutions espoused a desire for
a linkage to the inheritance of bourgeois revolutions, taking inspiration from
the repertoire of the modern age (ibid.). Therefore, ‘being modern’ is an
extremely complex process that transcends mere polarities. For example, while
the modernist revolutionary tradition since 1789 has been associated with
notions of heroism, self-sacrifice and certainty, modernity is typically
associated with Weber’s ideas of disenchantment, rationalization, professional
impersonality and formal legality (Cohen and Arato, 1992). Having discussed at
length where post-communism temporally fits on the spectrum between modernity
and postmodernity, the final section of this paper proceeds to put such
discussions into perspective, namely through a consideration of economic
development in Romania during the 1990s.
During the 1990s, the Romanian governments were
considered to be consistently failing to establish credibility in what regarded
democratic consolidation and market reform (Pop, 2007). The supposed
ideological rupture with the nation’s communist past was very much called into
question as ‘neo-communist’ political parties were in power until the end of
1996. Equally, the ‘shock therapy’ attempted in the period of 1997-1998 by the
‘democratic’ parties resulted in a three-year economic recession, the second
during that decade (ibid.). That said, by the early 2000s, Romania had become a
fully functional market economy and was reaching a standard of competitiveness
that allowed for significant progress in the process of EU accession (ibid.).
More importantly, Romania is very unique among the Central and East European
countries in what regards the intensity of its relationship with the IMF during
the 1990s, which thus accentuates a complexity in Romania’s post-communist
economic development during the 1990s.
The theoretical toolkit employed here in order to
understand this phenomenon heavily builds on the sociology of Pierre Bourdieu,
which is extremely sensitive to the ways in which macrostructures delineate and
delimit what is possible and impossible in micro-interactions (Leander, 2006).
Bourdieu’s understanding of the different spheres and fields of social life and
the way in which actors are embedded within these were developed through
anthropological and sociological research in national contexts, particularly
France and Algeria (ibid.). The national context remains very much relevant
here, for some of the determining factors in the relationship between Romania
and the IMF originate in domestic economic and political circumstances. Most
importantly, the post-communist transformations that took place can be defined
as processes of gradual differentiation of the economic and political spheres
or fields that had been tightly integrated under the communist regime (Adler,
1997). This therefore means that all of the elements that are characteristic of
fields in general, namely, identifiable actors, the distribution of their
assets, the structural relationship between the numerous positions of the
actors in the field, the stakes of field-specific struggles and the boundaries
that separate out the insiders from the outsiders all are in a process of
evolving (ibid.). Nevertheless, the actions of the Romanian economic and
political actors can only fully make sense and have significant consequences
when considered beyond domestic field-creation and with respect to the need to
use economic foreign policy to place the country within the international
political economy (Pop, 2007). Henceforth, to conceive of the international
state-system as a field is to
acknowledge that said field is constituted as a distinct sphere which only particular actors may have access to,
where there are clearly-agreed-upon rules of engagement and where the
distribution of resources is relatively stable and therefore has a structural
quality.
In order to fully understand the dynamic relationship
between states and the international field, in this case Romania and the IMF,
it is worth recalling another major element of Bourdieudian sociology: the
concept of habitus, which consists of
“systems of durable, transposable dispositions, structured structures
predisposed to function as structuring structures, that is, as principles which
generate and organize practices and representations that can be objectively
adapted to their outcomes without presupposing a conscious aiming at ends or an
express mastery of the operations necessary in order to attain them.’’
(Bourdieu, 1992: 58). In other words, structures manifest themselves in the
actors’ internalized sense of their
own place in a particular social context, or within a particular field, and the rationalizations that they employ in order to understand their
position (ibid.). By acting in this sense, often unconsciously, both individual
and collective actors structure distributions
of material power.
For Bourdieu, certain practices arise out of the
interwoven and dynamic interaction between habitus and field. However, the
practices that are most relevant for the study of the international sphere are
those associated with what Bourdieu (1982) identifies as the logic of honour and which brings along
with it the issue of contestation. This pressure to shield declared norms from
open contestation is visible in interactions in the international field;
because states and intergovernmental organizations embody the highest forms of
political authority in relation to their domestic constituencies and in
relation to each other, there is a heightened sense of danger about their
interactions (ibid.). As a result, high-level interactions between actors in
the international sphere occur in accordance with elaborate rules of protocol
that are supposed to shield and satisfy the sense of identity, and the sense of honour, of all the legitimate
participants (ibid.). Consequently, this Bourdieudian analysis of the
relationship between the state and the international political stage can serve
as a reinforcement of the Derridean critique of the hegemonic neoliberal
project and its subversion of socialist identity; that is, neoliberal ‘honour’
must be kept safe from the prospect of challenge at all costs.
As such, on one level, the relationship between the
successive Romanian governments of the 1990s and the IMF can be seen as an
example of attempts to maintain the existing social fabric and to reproduce
existing hierarchies. For example, the Romanian governments, throughout
repeated applications for international financial assistance, accepted all
conditions as supplicants who have to function according to established
practices and conventions; they did not give into the temptation to issue a
challenge to the IMF’s authority by, for instance, challenging its judgments
(Pop, 2007). A case in point is the 1997-1998 Democratic Convention of Romania
(CDR) government led by Victor Ciorbea. In its eagerness to demonstrate to the
outside world that Romania was a true neoliberal reformer, the government
implemented a shock therapy program that by and large ignored previous
experience with price liberalisation and the difficulties inherent in
implementing structural reform (Pasti, 1998). Eventually, the government was
forced to acknowledge the fact that ensuring social peace was rewarding in and
of itself, even in the eyes of foreign actors; by giving in to protesters and
delaying either the restructuring or closure of some of the greatest
loss-makers in the economy, Ciorbea strengthened Romania’s case as a factor of
political stability in the region (Pavel and Huiu, 2003). In general, thus, the
CDR enjoyed far greater trust and recognition on the part of their foreign counterparts
and this was perhaps the result of their unwavering pro-Western rhetoric (Pop,
2007). Consequently, this Bourdieudian discussion of economic development in
Romania during the 1990s and following the fall of communism lends credence to
the argument that post-communism has opened up a new space for understanding
modernity; one of constant struggle to redefine an identity and to find a place
in the new world created by drastic structural and political shifts.
In conclusion, this paper has provided an extensive
and elaborate examination of the phenomenon of post-communism by paying close
and careful attention to the modernity-postmodernity juxtaposition. The
neoliberal project, or struggle, is one that highlights the hegemony of
so-called campaigns to create ‘free-market economy’, which in reality serves as
a pretext to impose a certain politico-economic agenda, or to defend a sense of
‘honour’, as per Bourdieu’s understanding of honour. The consideration of Romania’s
relationship with the IMF is a case in point; governments’ desires to
emancipate the country and modernize it, as it were, were inevitably going to
be constrained by international influence, and national development was
equivalated to an alignment with Western post-communist economic projects.
Comments
Post a Comment